From http://www.atimes.com/atimes/China_Business/JJ02Cb03.html on Dec 16, 2008.
Page 1 of 5
CHINA'S
DOLLAR MILLSTONE, Part 4
Gold,
manipulation and domination
By Henry C K Liu
All over the world, trade in gold had
been the favored device for evading
national foreign exchange controls from
the end of World War II to 1971. In 1946, the Bretton Woods regime
adopted in 1944 became operational, thereby forbidding
the importation of gold for private speculative purposes in
signatory nations. Britain was a signatory but Portugal was not.
Thus a gold-smuggling operation between the Portugal colony
of Macau and the British territory of
Hong Kong flourished until 1974, two
years after the United States took the dollar off gold, in effect
abolishing the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, when
Hong Kong abolished a law that requires a special license to import
gold for re-export. Tiny Macau became one of the world's biggest
importers and re-exporters of gold during this period.
Instability
in the exchange value of the British pound sterling in the late 1960s
pushed Hong Kong, a British territory since 1841, to switch to a
gold-backed US dollar pegged at $35 per ounce of gold. Hong
Kong trading firms bought gold legally on the London gold market
beyond the reach of US law forbidding private purchase and ownership
of gold on US soil, at a pegged price of $35 per ounce. They
then passed it along to Macau gold syndicates for a service charge to
recast the gold into physical shapes suitable for smuggling back to
Hong Kong, where it could be sold at above-peg prices for use in
financial transactions around the world out of range of Bretton Woods
regulations. London -> Macau -> Hong Kong
-> World
From 1960 to 1980, Turkey
strictly regulated the flows of gold in and out of the country. The
government passed a law on the "Protection of the Value of
Turkish Currency" to control gold smuggling. During this period,
the price in the domestic market was around US$12 per ounce higher
than in international markets. Before 1980, when importing gold was
prohibited, smuggled gold volumes into the country reached 80
tons a year.
In 1980, together with a general policy
change on liberalization and globalization, the foreign exchange
market and a number of commodity markets were deregulated. In 1985,
the central bank was given responsibility for importing gold against
the Turkish lira. During this period, the average price difference
between the domestic and international markets decreased to US$7.65
per ounce. In 1993, further liberalization ended the central bank's
monopoly and allowed gold bullion imports and exports by authorized
market participants on a declaration basis. In 1992, the average
price difference between the domestic and international markets
decreased to US$1.28 per ounce.
The opening of the Istanbul
Gold Exchange (IGE) on July 26, 1995, and the price difference
between domestic and international markets decreased still further to
US$0.72 per ounce. This meant that Turkey's citizens were paying less
for gold but the Turkish currency was appreciating as the money
supply shrank to slow the economy.
In 1939, at the start of
World War ll, gold imports into British India were controlled or
banned. This British legacy of colonial exploitation was continued by
Indian government. Gold control laws were enacted that stopped all
legal gold imports into India. Gold smuggling continued the gold
traffic. The gold control laws corrupted four generations of
Western-trained Indian government officials and politicians, made
gold expensive in relation to Indian income and kept Indians in
poverty longer.
Overseas drain of gold from the US
By
1971, the US gold stock had declined by $10 billion, a 50% drop. At
the same time, foreign banks held $80 billion, eight times the amount
of gold remaining in US possession. A growing US balance-of-payments
deficit meant that foreign governments were accumulating large
amounts of dollars - in aggregate volume far
exceeding the US government's stock of gold. The central banks
of these governments could show up at any time at the gold window of
the US Treasury and insist on trading in their dollars for gold,
which would precipitate a run on the US gold
reserve.
The issue was not theoretical. By the 1960s,
many foreigners were buying gold at an artificially low price of $35
set by Bretton Woods and sold it in the black market for easy profit.
The result was that the US began to bleed gold
through her fiscal and trade deficits and by the increasing
amount of dollars sent overseas, know as euro-dollars. France under
Charles de Gaulle realized that this trend was unsustainable. The US
was printing more dollars than its gold holding could support and
dumping the dollars in world markets.
To deal with the
problem, president John F Kennedy approved the suggestion of newly
appointed undersecretary of the Treasury Robert Roosa that the US,
Britain, France, Germany and other European nations pool their gold
resources to prevent the commercial price for gold from exceeding the
Bretton Woods mandated rate of US 35 per ounce. Acting on this
suggestion, the central Banks of the US,
Britain, West Germany, France, Switzerland, Italy, Belgium, the
Netherlands, and Luxembourg set up the "London
Gold Pool" in early 1961.
The
London Gold Pool came unstuck when France under de Gaulle
pulled out and began to send the dollars earned by exporting to the
US back to the US and demanding gold
rather than Treasury debt paper in return. Under the terms of the
1944 Bretton Woods Agreement, France was
legally entitled to do just that. As the drain on US gold
became acute, the London Gold Pool folded in
April 1968 because it did not command enough gold to support
the price at $35 per ounce. The demand by foreigners for gold held by
the US surged.
George Pompidou, then as prime minister under
de Gaulle and later French president observed: "The
international monetary system is functioning poorly because it
gives advantages to the country issuing the reserve currency.
Such a country can have inflation by making others pay for it."
John Connally, Treasury secretary under president Richard
Nixon, had told foreign finance ministers that "the dollar was
America's currency, but your problem".
To solve the problem, France redeemed its dollar holdings in gold in
early August 1971 by sending a French
battleship to New York to take delivery of French gold from the vault
of the New York Federal Reserve Bank and to bring it to the
vault of the Banque de France in Paris. The French raised gold
reserves and dumped dollars. Banque de France eventually increased
its gold holding to 92% of its reserves.
Even Britain, the
ally with a "special relationship" jumped the monetary
ship. On August 11, 1971, the British ambassador in Washington
received instructions from London to go to the Treasury Department to
request the conversion of $3 billion into gold
and to have it moved from the United States Bullion Depository at
Fort Knox to the underground vault of the New York Federal Reserve
Bank, where foreign government gold was stored. US gold
reserves had dropped from 20,000 tons to 8,500 tons (32,150 troy
ounces = 1 metric ton). At $35 per ounce, 8,500 tons of gold had a
cash value of $9.56 billion. Four days later, on August 15, 1971,
President Nixon announced that the United States would no longer
redeem dollars for gold, making it the final
step in abandoning the gold standard.
The breakdown of
the Bretton Woods monetary system in 1971 was precipitated by
short-term capital movements out of the dollar into the key European
currencies, leading to the floating of the rising German mark and the
Dutch guilder. But the long-standing payments deficit of the US and
her deteriorating current account and fiscal account since 1965 were
the fundamental causes.
At first
the short-term capital flows of early 1971 signaled the reverse of
the great floods of money that had moved to the US between 1969 and
1970 when the US business cycle peaked and the Federal Reserve made
concerted effort belatedly to restrain the growth of the money
supply. The combination of inflation momentum and abrupt tight money
pushed interest rates to unconstructive levels. As usual, the Fed
response on dated incoming data caused its time-lagged response to
overshoot, exacerbating volatility. This is known in the market as
the Fed always falling behind the curve.
When real data on the US business cycle topping out finally
became visible, the Fed again belatedly eased monetary policy
excessively to cushion the fall already in process. As frequently in
previous crises, the time lag of the effect of Fed actions on market
behavior caused the Fed to overshoot both
coming and going. Dollar rates dropped precipitously in
November 1970 and money flooded back to Europe like a tidal wave. The
flow at first only reflected interest rate differentials, but as
always, interest-rate-driven flows induced
speculative runs.
The massive rush of funds into
Germany threatened to undermine Bundesbank efforts to contain
inflation in Germany. The German central bank opted to suspend the
fixed exchange rate of the mark and allowed it to rise against the
dollar to fight domestic inflation, against which Germans have a
historical phobia. A similar sequence of events ensued in the
Netherlands. The flight from the dollar continued and eventually
accelerated. US gold reserves were visibly inadequate to maintain
even the semblance of convertibility, forcing Nixon to close gold
convertibility to foreigners. After the gold window was formally
closed, the major currencies either floated or were shielded against
further dollar inflows by capital controls.
The silver
Hunts
The family of Texas oil patriarch H L Hunt was one of
the richest in America. The sons, Nelson Bunker and William Herbert,
played a very significant role in the discovery and development of
the oil fields in Libya, which were later nationalized by order of
Muammar al-Gaddafi. In 1973, the Hunt brothers decided to buy
precious metals as a hedge against inflation. Gold still could not be
legally held by private citizens at that time, so
the Hunts began to buy silver in large quantity. By 1979, the
Hunt Brothers, together with wealthy Mid-East investors, controlled a
pool of more than 200 million ounces of silver, equivalent to half
the world's deliverable supply.
When the Hunts began
accumulating silver back in 1973, the price per ounce was in the
$1.95 range. By early in 1979, the price had risen to $5. By
September 1979, the price reached $11. But in January 1980, the price
went to the $50 range, peaking at $54. Gold hit
a then historic high of $850 in 1980, making the silver/gold
ratio at 15.74/1, very close to the historical
ration of 15/1. It looked like that the Hunts were restoring
the gold standard with bimetal ratio.
Once the silver market
was cornered by the Hunts, outsiders joined the chase. The Hunts and
other silver traders were financing their silver buys and holdings
with bank loans in futures contracts. A combination of changed
trading rules on the New York Metals Market (COMEX) and the
intervention of the Federal Reserve punctured the speculative bubble
and the price of silver began to slide, culminating in a 50% one-day
decline on March 27, 1980 as the price plummeted from $21.62 to
$10.80. As the price of silver fell, the Hunt Brothers were unable to
meet a $100 million margin call. [Jim
Sinclair worked for the Hunts during this period. He's said that the
problem with a corner is exiting your position: there's no one to
whom to sell it.]
The collapse of the silver market
meant countless losses for speculators. The Hunt brothers declared
bankruptcy. By 1987, their liabilities had grown to nearly $2.5
billion against assets of $1.5 billion. In August 1988, the Hunts
were convicted of conspiring to manipulate the silver market.
Soviet monetary system
The ruble has been the
Russian unit of currency for about 500 years. From 1710, the ruble
was divided into 100 kopeks. The amount of precious metal in a ruble
varied over time. In a 1704 currency reform, Peter I standardized the
ruble to 28 grams of silver. While ruble coins were silver, higher
denominations were minted in gold and platinum. By the end of the
18th century, the ruble was set to 18 grams of silver or 1.2 grams of
gold, with a ratio of 15:1 for the values of the two metals. In 1828,
platinum coins were introduced with 1 ruble equal to 3.451 grams.
On December 17, 1885, a new standard was adopted that reduced
the gold content to 1.161 grams, pegging the gold ruble to four
French francs. This rate was revised in 1897 to 1 ruble =
two-and-two-thirds francs, or 0.774 grams gold. With
the outbreak of the World War 1 in 1914, Russia dropped the gold
standard and the ruble fell in value to cause hyperinflation
in 1920s. Between 1921 and 1922 inflation in the USSR reached 213%.
In 1992, the first year of post-Soviet economic reform,
inflation was 2,520%, the major cause being the decontrol of most
prices in January. In 1993 the annual rate was 840%, and in 1994,
224%. The ruble devalued from about 40 to the US dollar in 1991 to
about 30,000 in 1999. In 2008, the ruble exchange rate is about 25.5
to the dollar. Russia's inflation rate in 2008 is around 3.2%.
Following World War II, the Soviet government implemented a
redenomination of the currency to reduce the amount of money in
circulation. This only affected paper money. Old rubles were revalued
at one tenth of their face value. The 1961 redenomination was a
repeat of the 1947 reform, with the same terms applying. The Soviet
ruble of 1961 was formally equal to 0.987412 gram of gold, but,
similar to the US, the exchange for gold was
not available to the general public. Following the breakup of
the Soviet Union in 1991, the ruble remained the currency of the
Russian Federation. A new set of banknotes was issued in the name of
Bank of Russia in 1993. During the period of high inflation of the
early 1990s, the ruble was significantly devalued.
Soviets
and the Marshall Plan
The Marshall Plan
was more than an aid program to help Europe recover from war damage.
It sought to restructure Western European economies away from their
prewar socialist direction and launch them on a
path towards US-style market capitalism based on a new
monetary regime of a gold-backed dollar
and to keep budding European social democracy from mutating into
populist communism through elections.
The strategic
geopolitical purpose was to integrate Western Europe firmly into
postwar Pax Americana of free-market fundamentalism and
a regional military alliance in the form of North Atlantic Treaty
Organization (NATO) based on collective security, [(]having
rejected the lesson of the role of interlinked alliances in igniting
World War I[)].
The Marshall Plan was the linchpin of US strategy to neutralize a
perceived rising Soviet threat. It helped to trigger the Cold War.
The Soviet leadership responded to post-Roosevelt US policy
based on Soviet experience with the West before, during and after
World War ll. This experience led Moscow to a policy that was not
simply fuelled by a conditional reflex of anti-Americanism, which
during the Roosevelt era had been kept in deep abeyance.
The
Munich Pact of 1938 followed Franco-British rejection of two
successive Soviet offers (in 1934 and 1937) to form an alliance
against Germany in Europe and Japan in Asia, thus pushing the
USSR to enter the Soviet-German Non-aggression Pact of August 23,
1939, less than a year after Munich. From the
Soviet perspective, Munich was a Western scheme to turn Nazi
aggression eastward and use German fascism to counter Soviet
communism. The Soviet-German Non-aggression Pact was an
attempt to turn the table back against capitalism by freeing up
fascism against it.
Munich convinced the USSR that the
Western powers were pursuing a policy of selective appeasement only
toward German eastward expansion and were not interested in joining
the Soviet Union in an anti-fascist alliance promoted through a
popular front. In addition, there was concern about the possibility
that Britain and France would stay neutral in a war initiated by
Germany against the USSR, hoping that the two warring Eastern powers
would wear each other out and put an end to both the Bolshevik Soviet
Union and Nazi Germany.
In this sense, Munich was less a
strategy of appeasement to secure peace than a Western capitalist
democracy strategy of directing war eastward
between fascism and communism. (See Beyond
Munich: Geostrategy and betrayal, Asia Times Online, April 28,
2007.)
By late 1941, and with the USSR under attack from
Germany, Western powers had not yet opened a second front (and would
not do so until June 1944), Moscow had reasons to seek a separate
peace with Germany. Churchill and Roosevelt were fully aware of this
possibility.
After taking over as prime minister in the
spring of 1940, Churchill refused to pledge that Britain would cease
hostilities against Germany in the event of an internal coup to
topple the Third Reich. This policy is known in British diplomacy as
"absolute silence". Yet Churchill was flabbergasted, and
later claimed that he had not been consulted, when after Roosevelt
and Churchill met at Casablanca in January 1943 the idealistic US
president emerged from the meeting to tell the
world that the US and Britain would accept nothing short of
unconditional surrender from Germany. Roosevelt needed to do
this because he was aware that the US public
did not want to go to war to save old Europe, only to save the world
from tyranny.
Churchill later claimed that he had not
been consulted but had to go along for the sake of the Atlantic
Alliance. Churchill had in the back of his mind the use of Germans to
resist postwar communist incursion into Europe, and was interested
in preserving the Wehrmacht for that purpose. He knew that no
Wehrmacht officer would support a coup against Hitler only to have
his country invaded, occupied, and humiliated by the Allies that
included a communist power. For the German military, better to stand
by Nazi Germany, even if it meant following Hitler's madness toward
total destruction, than to commit such dishonorable high treason.
But Roosevelt, driven by US public opinion, left Churchill no
room to maneuver. Unlike Churchill, Roosevelt
saw the possibility and merit of peaceful co-existence between
capitalist and communist nations and did not look forward with relish
to the need or value of a Cold War.
Coming when it did
in January 1943, the same month the German 6th Army was defeated at
Stalingrad, the Roosevelt unconditional surrender proclamation
prompted Ulrich von Hassel, who had used his international contacts
to arrange secret meetings with British and American officials, and
had hoped that a successful coup would translate into an honorable
peace treaty with Britain and the US, to conclude that the
unconditional surrender proclamation had bailed
out Hitler from domestic opposition over his military disaster at
Stalingrad.
Risks of a separate peace
Roosevelt's
unconditional surrender demand had its own logic. For Roosevelt, it
was vital not to give Stalin any incentive that would tempt him to
strike a separate deal with Germany that would lead to a separate
peace. In World War I, generals Paul Von Hindenberg and Erich
Ludendorff had pulled off such a separate peace with new Soviet
Russia in early 1918, but it came too late to allow them to move
their forces westward to smash the Anglo-French lines before US
forces arrived.
It was very likely that the Allies might
never have won World War II if Stalin, having regained the 1939
Soviet border, suddenly backed out of the war to allow German forces
on the Eastern Front to be diverted towards the West. Moreover, the
United States was eager to get the Soviet Union to declare war on
Japan to reduce projected heavy US casualties since the Manhattan
Project to develop the atomic bomb was still years away from
completion in 1942 and success had not been guaranteed.
On
June 5, 1947, Secretary of State George C Marshall spoke at Harvard
University and outlined the Marshall Plan. Europe, still devastated
by the war, had just survived one of the harshest winters on record.
The nations of Europe had nothing to sell for hard currency
with which to buy food and fuel, and the postwar social
democratic governments in most countries were unwilling and unable to
adopt the draconian proposals for recovery advocated by old-line
classical market economists. Something had to be done, both for
humanitarian reasons and also to stop the potential spread of
communism in Western Europe.
The US offered for European
relief up to $20 billion ($200 billion in 2008 dollars, or 10% of its
GDP which would come to $1.4 trillion in 2008), but only if the
European nations could get together and draw up a plan to act as a
single cooperative economic unit. Marshall also offered aid to the
Soviet Union and its allies in Eastern Europe, but Stalin denounced
the program as a trick to spread market capitalism in the Soviet
Union and refused to participate. Ironically, Soviet rejection made
passage of the Marshall Plan through congress possible. In 1947,
anticommunism in the US was much stronger than anti-Americanism in
the Soviet Union.
While Europe was devastated by war, the US
was blessed with record-breaking wheat harvests in 1944 and 1945. Its
defense industry had produced for the war 196,000 aircraft, with
96,356 in 1944 alone, and more than 40
billion bullets. In 1943 alone, the US produced 19 million tons of
merchant ships, up from prewar production of 600,000 tons. Gross
national product (GNP) doubled from less than $100 billion in 1940 to
more than $200 billion in 1945. Corporate profits also doubled from
about $6 billion in 1940 to $12 billion four years later.
By
1944, the US was able to spend on war more than its entire national
income in all previous time in peace. More than $50 billion of
lend-lease goods were sent to allies,
mostly to Britain and to a lesser amount to the USSR. US national
income tripled to $198 billion by the end of the war from $72 billion
in 1939.
Unlike the rest of the war-torn world, the
US had never had it so good, which left the national psyche
with greatly reduced phobia against war. For
the US public, war meant prosperity and inspiring entertainment
as portrayed in Hollywood war movies. Operationally, both world wars
were limited wars, for the US fought only on foreign land. The
positive socio-economic impacts from these two conflicts left the US
with a cavalier mentality for future limited wars, first Korea,
then Vietnam, then Kosovo, then Iraq, then Afghanistan, then Iraq
again and possible Iran before long.
In one stroke,
World War ll swept away the blight of economic depression that had
afflicted the US for 12 stagnant years before the Japanese attack on
Pearl Harbor. Roosevelt's lowest unemployment rate during the New
Deal years was still over 14%. In 1945, the unemployment rate was
close to 1%, even with a much larger labor force, adding 30% more
workers to the total workforce of 64 million, including 3 million
housewives.
Regional economic disparity was moderated. The
depressed south received a disproportionate volume of defense
contracts, including nearly $6 billion of federally financed
industrial facilities. Wartime federal spending gave birth to the
"Sun Belt" of new high-tech manufacturing, ironically a
region that would in time form the electoral base for ideological
assault on government intrusion in the economy.
The National
Bureau of Economic Research showed that whereas in 1929 the richest
1% received 16% of the national income, in 1948 they received only
8%. World War II had a significant effect on the equalization of
income and wealth in the US, but economic
democracy did not last long. In 2007, the richest 1% in the US
received 22% of the national income. The top marginal income tax rate
in 1947 was 86.45% while the top rate in 2008 is 35%. The highest
rate was 94% in 1944-45. Any way you cut it, the rich in the US have
been favored by the government since soon after World War ll ended.
Economic democracy receded soon after the war to defend democracy
ended.
World War II amplified to
unprecedented proportions the intrusive role of the federal
government in US society in the process of defending freedom
abroad. After the war, the Federal Bureau of Investigation (FBI)
turned from a federal agency against organized crime to one that
routinely violated the civil rights of large number of citizens in
its mission to protect freedom. Ideological witch hunts were
conducted in all levels of society, reaching even to the highest
level of government, culminating in General
Marshall being accused of being a communist sympathizer.
World War ll also turned the US into a superpower at the
expense of European powers, allies and enemies alike. The nation that
had entered the war to protect the weak and the poor of the world
abandoned the purpose of the "good war" after the death of
Franklin D Roosevelt, its great populist leader, and turned its
support towards preserving post-war Western colonialism in the name
of anticommunism.
Harry S Truman, an insecure leader who
became president by default, allowed himself to be manipulated by
Winston Churchill not only to see communism as an evil ideology but
also as an opportunity to exploit anticommunism
to collect the geopolitical dividends of victory. It nurtured
US "exceptionism" in foreign
policy and gave the young nation a messianic mission of enlarging
democracy and Christian values around the world, to distant lands
whose names most US leaders could not pronounce properly and most US
citizens had never heard of in their daily lives.
The postwar
US began to view itself as God's new chosen nation and marveled at
its own holy perfection. It transformed itself into the role of "the
indispensable nation" as a justification for hegemony. The only
challenge to postwar US hegemony came from its former wartime ally,
the USSR, the "evil empire", as president Reagan later came
to call it.
Soviets reject Marshall Plan - onset of Cold
War
The opening salvo of the Cold War was Soviet rejection of
the Marshall Plan. In saving Europe from war-induced starvation, the
Marshall Plan also saved the US economy from a repeat of the postwar
depression of World War I. The financial aid was denominated in US
dollars, to be used to buy goods from the US shipped across the
Atlantic on US merchant vessels.
By 1953, the United States
had pumped $13 billion into the Marshall Plan account, moderating the
adverse impact of military demobilization on the US domestic economy.
Moreover, the plan included former arch-enemy West Germany, which was
thus reintegrated into the European community. It
neutralized war reparations normally required of a vanquished country
through the division of the German nation into capitalistic
West and socialist East.
More significantly, the Marshall
Plan established the US dollars as the reserve
currency for intra-European and international trade and laid
the economic foundation for gold-backed dollar dominance, which
turned into a fiat currency after Nixon closed the gold window in
1971 and emerged as dollar hegemony with globalization of finance
after the end of the Cold War.
Aside from helping to put
Europe economically back on its feet, the
Marshall Plan led to the Schuman Plan, the Coal and Iron Community
and the Common Market, and pointed to what may yet evolve into
an economically and politically united Europe. The Schuman Plan in
turn led to the European Atomic Energy
Community (Euratom), which was signed (along with the EEC
Treaty) in Rome on March 25, 1957, and entered into force on January
1, 1958. It was one of the founding treaties of the EU, which called
for support for nuclear power across the EU and is the only treaty
that supports the development of a particular energy source.
However, currently in the EU seven
member states do not have nuclear power, while four more have the
political objective of phasing out their nuclear power
programs. Throughout the EU there are no reactors under construction
since May 2008. Despite this the Euratom Treaty remains.
Soviet
policymakers understandably viewed the Marshall Plan as a US strategy
to exploit the war-ravaged conditions of Europe to establish US
domination through monetary imperialism.
To Soviet leaders, the Marshall Plan was a realpolitik strategy
cloaked in humanistic ideals. The USSR rejection of the Marshall Plan
turned the Cold War into economic position warfare.
While US
policies militarily assumed a defensive geo-strategic position
against communist expansionism, its economic policies took on
aggressively assertive initiatives designed to expand the reach of
the capitalist system throughout the world. From this perspective,
Soviet rejection of the Marshall Plan was a natural response of a
socialist state trying to resist external market pressure and
internal revisionist agitation for reintegration of hard-won
socialism back into the capitalist Western economy, and the
subordination of new socialist nations to new domination by the
capitalist West.
In 1947, Soviet economist and Hungarian
expatriate Evgenii Varga proposed the notion of a
"Third World" that would be a decisive arena of
opportunity and conflict in the post-World War ll era. The
First World was occupied by the two superpowers: US and the
USSR, and Second World was occupied by
the major powers that were allies of either the two superpowers. The
main arena of opportunity and conflict was in the Third World
countries in Asia, Africa, and Central and South America. Since World
War II, all limited wars, some lasting longer than the world wars,
have been fought in the Third World
The Soviet leadership
also viewed the Marshal Plan as an attempt to use economic aid not
only to consolidate a Western European bloc, but also to undermine
recently won, and still somewhat tenuous, Soviet geopolitical gains
in Eastern Europe. It feared that the US economic aid program sought
to transform the new chain of Soviet-oriented buffer states into a
revamped version of the "cordon sanitaire" of the interwar
years. The plan appeared to aim at the reintegration of Eastern
Europe into the capitalist economic system of the West, with all the
political ramification that implied.
Thus the Marshall Plan,
conceived by US policymakers primarily as a defensive measure to
stave off economic collapse in Western Europe to keep communism from
electoral triumph in European domestic politics, proved
indistinguishable to the Soviet
leadership from an offensive attempt to subvert Soviet security
interests.
Offensive aspects of Marshall Plan
The
Marshall Plan was openly offensive in that its authors, notably
George F Kennan, whose writings formed the basis of the Truman
Doctrine to support any nation economically and militarily to prevent
their falling under Soviet control, did indeed aim at luring some of
the Eastern European states out of the Soviet orbit and integrate
them into the Western European economy. In this sense, the economic
motives behind the Marshall Plan were undeniably more than just a
geo-strategy to counter Soviet expansionism. It was rather a
plan to constrict and reduce socialism in Eastern Europe.
In
conversations with Harold Stassen, a perennial candidate for the
Republican presidential nomination, Stalin particularly focused his
queries on the possibility of government intervention heading off a
future economic crisis. And he seemed more optimistic than Stassen
that such intervention could succeed. Stassen, a Roosevelt Republican
who lost the nomination as Republican candidate against Truman in the
1948 presidential election to Thomas Dewey, ran for president a total
of nine times, the last being in 1992.
Stassen delivered the
keynote address at the 1940 Republican Convention to help secure the
nomination for Wendell Willkie, when senator Robert Taft of Ohio
stressed that the US needed to prevent the New Deal from using the
international crisis to extend socialism at home. Had Stassen
received the Republican nomination in 1948, he might have defeated
Truman to reach an understanding with the Soviet Union to prevent the
Cold War.
Time Magazine in its Monday, May 12, 1947
edition reported:
Last week, Harold Stassen, peripatetic Republican presidential candidate, disclosed the full report of his recent conversation with Russia's Generalissimo Joseph Stalin. It went something like this:
Stassen: Generalissimo Stalin ... I would be interested to know if you think [our] two economic systems can exist together in the same modern world in harmony ...
Stalin: Of course, they can ...
Stassen: ... There have been many statements about not being able to cooperate. Some of these were made by the Generalissimo himself ...
Stalin: It's not possible that I said that the two economic systems could not cooperate ...
Stassen: The statements I referred to are those made by you at the 18th Communist Party Congress in 1939 and the Plenary Session in 1937 - statements about "capitalist encirclement" and "monopoly ..."
Stalin: There was not a single Party Congress or Plenary Session ... at which I said or could have said that cooperation between the two systems was impossible.
Stassen: I had an informal talk with Mr Molotov ... and it developed into an invitation to visit Russia on the occasion of my trip to Europe.
Stalin: Things are in very bad shape in Europe as a whole. Is that true?
Stassen: Yes, in general, but there are some countries ... Switzerland, Czechoslovakia -
Stalin: Those are small countries ...
Stassen: The low production of coal in the Ruhr has caused a shortage of coal throughout Europe.
Stalin: Yes. It is very strange ...
Stassen: It is fortunate that we have had such large production of coal in the United States ...
Stalin: Things are not bad in the United States.
Stassen: Our [the US] problem now is to see to it that we do not have a depression, an economic crisis. [1947]
Stalin: Do you expect a crisis?
Stassen: ... I believe we can regulate our capitalism and stabilize our production and employment at a high level without any serious crisis ...
Stalin: The Government must be vested with wide powers to accomplish that ... Magazine analysts and the American press carry open reports to the effect that an economic crisis will break out.
Stassen: ... The problem is one of leveling off at high production and stabilizing ...
Stalin: The regulation of production?
Stassen: The regulation of capitalism.
Stalin: But what about businessmen? Will they be prepared to be regulated?
Stassen: No. Some will have objections.
Stalin: Yes, they do ...
The influential economist Varga suggested in 1946 that the
increased role played in the economy by the governments of the
Western capitalist states might make possible the emergence of a
limited form of economic planning in those economies after the war.
With such planning, Varga contended, these economies might
be able to avoid economic crises of the type that had caused
the Great Depression in the 1930s. (See National
planning and the American myth, Asia Times Online, June 13,
2002).
The implication was that Western market economies
would be stabilized by adopting aspects of war
planning in peace time, using an enlarged public sector to
counterbalance the volatile business cycle. Such views coincided with
those expressed by Joseph Schumpeter's 1942 work Capitalism,
Socialism and Democracy and later given further analysis by Hyman
Minsky's work on financial instability. As Western capitalist powers
adopted mixed economies, they would be less aggressive against
communism. Consequently a moderate Soviet policy of cooperation with
the Western powers might pay large peace dividends fro the whole
world.
Varga's contention that US confidence in its
capitalist economy would reduce US aggressiveness against communism
was obvious wishful thinking, given the ideological wind of the
Truman era. As it turned out, the enlarged public sector in the US
was mostly concentrated in defense spending. Still Varga's prediction
that market capitalism would be saved through planning and Keynesian
intervention held for half a century until the US went on a wholesale
market deregulation binge in the Reagan era.
The credit
crisis that began in August 2007 appears to be spinning out of
control with a high probability that financial capitalism will be
drowned by excessive debt beyond the power of the government to
rescue. How this mess will finally play out over the course of the
next few years is hard to predict because of the uncertainty of
government policy and action.
One thing is certain: when
the dust finally settles, the global economy will be fundamentally
different from what it was before 2007. In many ways,
countries with emerging economies such as China, India and Brazil,
can affect the shape of the new global economy if their leaders have
the wisdom and creativity to forge a new direction, instead of
continuing to play passive supporting roles to a dying system.
In
the latter part of 1947, once confrontation had come to dominate
Soviet-US relations, Varga would be
publicly criticized in the Soviet press and forced
to recant this views, which by then no longer comported with
the thrust of Soviet response to hostile US posture. But in April of
that year, Stalin in his conversations with Stassen was merely
gathering information from a high US source to confirm his impression
that despite some economic difficulties, the Western economies were
not on the verge of collapse, nor was the US moving towards a mixed
economy. The lack of progress at the December 1945 Moscow conference
to discuss occupation of Germany, peace establishment, and Far East
issues signaled only that Stalin was holding out for a better deal on
Germany, primarily on reparations, and not to start a Cold War.
In
May 1948, Moscow tried to counter the creation of the Organization
for European Economic Cooperation (OEEC), which was the institutional
embodiment of the Marshall Plan, by proposing the establishment of "a
committee for the development of economic relations between European
states" under the auspices of the UN Economic Commission for
Europe. The OEEC later became an international organization of some
30 countries, some outside of Europe, that accept the principles of
representative democracy and free market economies with the name
Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
Imminent crisis of capitalism
In the fall of 1948,
the debate among Soviet academic experts about the imminent general
crisis of capitalism was about Soviet policy on where the
US-dominated Western bloc was heading and what Soviet response to its
likely development ought to be. The USSR in January 1949 inaugurated
the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, later known as Comecon.
To Eastern European officials invited for the occasion, Soviet
leaders suggested Western European allies of the US, particularly
Italy and France, could be pulled loose from the US if they were pit
in a position of being critically dependent on the Soviet supply of
raw materials. In 2008. the European Union, dependent on Russia for
34% of its imported oil and 40% of imported gas, did not venture
beyond verbal condemnations over Russian invasion of Gerogia.
Soviet planners thought that Comecon, by creating a raw
material base for the whole of Europe, would become more important
than the Cominform, the official forum of the international communist
movement since the dissolution of the Comintern. Cominform was
founded in September 1947 in response to divergences among eastern
European governments on whether or not to attend the Paris Conference
on Marshall Aid in July 1947. Stalin was quoted as saying that he
"does not attach much importance to military matters", as
he saw little probability of war in the next eight to 10 years.
Stalin's prediction was wrong. Five years later, in 1951, the Korea
War was started by US client state South Korea.
Russia viewed
the end of the Cold War not as the beginning of a new equitable world
order of peace and prosperity for all, but a world dominated by a US
driven by a philosophy of confrontation with the assumption that it
was empowered by destiny to do anything it wants.
Now Russia,
boosted by its energy leverage drawn from a commodity price structure
largely engineered by US policy, is pushing back by copying
US post-Cold War unilateralism. In marching into Georgia,
Russia did not bother to seek United Nations diplomatic cover.
Topping the list of Russian grievances with post-Cold War US
aggressiveness is the expansion of NATO to Russia's sphere of
influence and the planned basing of a US anti-missile system in
former Soviet satellites Poland and the Czech Republic. "In
their eyes, this is payback time," admits Jack Matlock,
former US ambassador to the Soviet Union during the Reagan
administration. "We have set some very bad precedents for
Russia."
The US system of relying on private defense
contractors was in a better position to reap economic benefits from
nuclear and conventional armament than the Soviet system of state
enterprises. The strategy to bankrupt the USSR with arms spending was
essentially the one that Ronald Reagan employed to win the Cold War.
But the key factor for Soviet economic failure was its decision to
engage Western capitalist markets denominated in dollars, which the
US could print at will after 1971, while the USSR had to earn through
trade.
By joining Western markets, the USSR found it
increasingly difficult to fund with socialist sovereign credit
denominated in rubles its share of the arms race with the US. After
the Soviet leadership allowed the Soviet economy to fall into the
trap of needing dollars to achieve Soviet planning goals, it was a
matter of time before the socialist system in the USSR would
collapse.
Ironically, the fall of the USSR launched the US on
a path of national hubris divergent from
its core national interest. In 1951, the academic and pioneer in the
field of international relations theory Hans Morgenthau published In
Defense of the National Interest, in which he warned US
policymakers about confusing two important issues: Russian
imperialism and genuine revolution.
American foreign policy ought not to have the objective of bringing the blessings of some social and political system to all the world or of protecting all the world from the evils of some other system. [...] If we allow ourselves to be diverted from this objective of safeguarding our national security, and if instead we conceive of the American mission in some abstract, universal, and emotional terms, we may well be induced, against our better knowledge and intent, yet by the very logic of the task in hand, to raise the banner of universal counter-revolution abroad and of conformity in thought and action at home. In that manner we shall jeopardize our external security, promote the world revolution we are trying to suppress, and at home make ourselves distinguishable perhaps in degree, but not in kind, from those with which we are locked in ideological combat....
It is not an exaggeration to note that much of the national
security problems faced by the US after the end of the Cold War were
created by US policy.
Ownership of the means of
production
The defining characteristic of a socialist system
is the public ownership of the means of production. Karl Marx
observed that the historical-cultural pattern of the ownership of the
means of production (OMP) gave rise to the social phenomenon of class
and the politics of class struggle.
Membership in either
class, bourgeoisie of proletariat, is defined by the individual's
relationship to the means of production. When workers, through their
pension funds, participate indirectly in OMP as shareholders, they
become members of the petite bourgeoisie. Self-employed professionals
are also members of the petite bourgeoisie, even as they are
increasingly corporatized. For a market system to remain balanced,
the public sector needs to be dominant.
Minsky pointed out in
his 1996 paper "Uncertainty and the Institutional Structure of
Capitalist Economies" that capitalism is an ever-evolving
construct that recently entered a new stage: money manager
capitalism. In this form of capitalism, nearly all businesses are
organized as corporations; pension and mutual funds are the
predominant owners of financial assets; and managers of these funds
are judged solely on the total return on fund assets (dividends and
interest plus appreciation in share value). One consequence of the
money manager structure is predominance of short-run considerations
in decision making. A robust public sector is needed to rebalance
excessive uncertainty in the private sector.
Two important
points need to be borne in mind in understanding the concept of
ownership of the means of production. The first point is that private
ownership of the means of production is more than owning physical and
intellectual property, or owning the financial capital behind it. The
second point is that private ownership of the means of production in
a capitalist system refers to a socio-cultural practice in which a
small number of individuals within a larger corporation, namely
shareholders represented by the board of directors, operating under
the capitalist law of private property rights and the sanctity of
contracts as if the corporation were one single individual, can
control and decide what is done with all the profit created by the
entire corporation composed largely of workers who are legally
disfranchised of their economic rights merely because they do not own
the means of production.
As represented by management under
the supervision of the board of directors, these absentee owners of
the means of production do not have anything to do with the operation
of the corporation besides ownership of its capital. When
corporations make good profits, only their management and
shareholders benefit. Workers are paid a fixed wage and generally do
not receive bonuses based on profit earned by the corporation that
employ them. This may be legal and appear fair under the doctrine of
private ownership rights, but it is the fundamental injustice of
capitalism.
While shareowners of a corporation, members of
the bourgeoisie class by definition, contribute only financial
capital that enhances the productivity of workers, and workers,
members of the proletariat class, produce the profit, shareholders
command complete legal control over that profit and how it is used
and distributed.
The owning bourgeoisie have complete legal
control over both how much the working proletariat are paid in wages
and complete legal control over how the profit from worker
productivity is used, thus giving rise to a class division.
In
Chinese political nomenclature, the term bourgeoisie stands for the
"propertied class" and the term proletariat stands for the
"property-less class". The politics of class struggle is a
battle between uneven power commanded by capital and labor. Under a
central banking regime in a market economy, non-inflationary monetary
policy requires the maintenance of "structural unemployment",
thus systemically weakening the bargaining power of labor against
capital, unionism or no unionism.
Workers become their own
oppressors
Charles Dickens wrote on the inhumanity of
capitalism as a natural outcome of the Industrial Revolution to
promote reform. But Marx and Engels wrote on the structural
contradiction of capitalism to show that even if workers were treated
more humanely by capital as an enlightened utilitarian necessity,
capitalism will still not escape collapse from its internal
contradiction.
The introduction of meta-wage benefits via
pension funds turns classical capitalism into mass capitalism, making
workers simultaneously into their own oppressors through a system
that allows capital in the form of labor's own retirement savings to
continue to oppress labor. The search for high return on workers
pension funds is pushing wages down everywhere in the globalized
economy and relocating jobs from high-wage economies to low wage
economies. The neoliberal name for capitalism is market economy. The
concept of a labor market is merely a modern version of slavery.
Capitalist bias notwithstanding, labor
is not a factor of production. It is the core
component in the economy around which factors of production,
such as capital, land, technology, organization, and so forth are
applied to increase labor productivity. Marx considered it a
reification to treat labor as just another factor of production.
Workers are people who should not be used as things, with profit they
create extracted to benefit solely others who own things that workers
use to be more productive. Return on capital should not be achieved
through robbing labor of its fair share of the fruits of workers'
labor.
Profit should only be realizable pari passu
with wage increases. As corporate revenue rises, wages must rise with
it to prevent obscene profits. Rather, corporate profit should be
shared with labor in the from of wage bonuses along with dividends to
shareholders.
Privatization of the
public sector is an abdication of government responsibility to
the governed. It is economically unsound, financially inefficient and
socially unjust when national public infrastructure, either physical
or social, are privatized.
The public
sector is not merely another component of the national
economy. It is the critical component that defines
the limits of the globalized market in a functioning sovereign state.
Minsky pointed out that a sizable and strong government sector is
indispensable for a capitalist market economy to maintain
macroeconomic stability and avoid recurring deep recessions. In a
globalized economy, national public sectors are necessary to maintain
global macroeconomic stability.
Privatization of the public
sector exposes the capitalist market economy to cyclical disasters
that require nationalization measures to bail out, as the recent
collapse of the finance sector of the US economy aptly illustrates.
Even in the boom phase of the business cycle, privatization of the
pubic sector drives socioeconomic resources and development to where
there is highest profit rather than where the nation's most critical
needs are located. The nature of private finance is such that
privatized public enterprises are forced by market pressure to focus
on the short term, often leading them toward long-term problems and
even insolvency.
Privatization of the public sector provides
needed public services only to those who can afford them rather than
to all who need them as a matter of rights of citizenship. The
dilemma over universal health care and insurance in the US is an
obvious example. The market by its very nature rewards the
financially strong and punishes the financially weak, in opposition
to the function of government to protect the weak from the strong.
The market is the venue of choice for owners of capital,
notwithstanding that the market value of capital is basically defined
by state actions, such as monetary policy, interstate trade and
antitrust regulations, tax policies, and above all by the
productivity of labor.
Fundamentally, capital is merely idle
assets when deprived of the opportunity to invest in enhancing the
productivity of labor. Capital is merely an auxiliary factor of
production. Without capital, labor can still produce, albeit at a
lower productivity rate, but without labor, capital cannot exit
[exist?]. This is why capital,
when allowed to move freely, tends to go to where workers are and
where worker productivity is underdeveloped. This fundamental
truth is often distorted by the supporters of capitalism who promote
the flawed concept that capital is the driving force in a capitalist
economy and therefore must be given preferred advantage or it will
move to another economy that does.
Dollar hegemony operating
on a globalized trade regime pushes capital to where wages are lowest
without any intention of developing global parity in worker
productivity. [But you get the effect even
without the intention!] The sole aim is to maximize the return
on capital with lowest wages. For centuries, capitalism prospered
because it enhanced labor productivity that yielded rising wages. For
the past two decades, free market capitalism has worked to drive
wages down throughout the global economy [well,
by employing the mass army of the unemployed ...], a trend
that will spell self-destruction.
Further, just as the rich
can enjoy a life of riches only if they control money, but not when
money controls them, an
economy can prosper only when its
workers
control the capital needed to enhance their productivity.
It is a very American idea that workers should be able to become rich
by their labor, an idea deeply rooted in the founding of the new
nation. The founding
fathers of the United States considered the concept of financial
capital unnatural and an unholy obstacle to the inalienable right of
the pursuit of happiness.
On February 12,
2005, I wrote:
The US Declaration of Independence issued on July 4, 1776, states that to secure "inalienable rights", among which are life, liberty and the pursuit of happiness, "governments are instituted among men". It goes on to accuse King George III of England of having "abdicated Government here, by declaring us out of his Protection". The declaration characterizes England as a failed state and justifies the separation of the American colonies from it to institute a new government. Yet privatization, a movement to abdicate government by declaring the people out of the government's protection and placing them at the mercy of the market, has since gathered much ideological support in the name of liberty. (See The privatization wave.
Operationally, the public sector performs a stabilizing effect on
volatile business cycles inherent in the private sector market.
Private-sector market participants can then be allowed to fail from
their own business misjudgments without the risk of bringing the
entire economy down because the public sector can keep the economy
going while orderly market correction takes place in the private
sector.
'Too big to fail' syndrome
The "too
big to fail" syndrome would be less likely to surface amongst
private enterprises. If Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had remained
government entities, and not been privatized, with the original
mandate to provide government subsidies to low- and moderate-income
families not overridden by profit incentives and the income ceiling
for qualifying for government guaranteed mortgages not amended beyond
low- and moderate-income levels, the housing bubble crisis of 2007
would have been less systemic.
Transnational investment banks
and private equity firms such as Goldman Sachs, Blackstone, the
Carlyle Group, Merrill Lynch, Morgan Stanley and so forth are eager
to pounce on juicy privatized public assets such as infrastructure
projects worldwide. But privatization of the public sector (the sale
or lease of public assets) means governments will be relinquishing
control over and responsibility for key infrastructure for the common
good for the term of the sales. It usually also means higher fees for
users, since private borrowing tends to be more costly than sovereign
credit, and investors always insist on taking their profits off the
top from gross revenue, thus increasing user fees and reducing the
cost-competitiveness of those users depending on such infrastructure
for efficient operation.
And rising user fees seldom
translate into improved service. To the contrary, surveys have shown
that in-house operation of publicly provided services is generally
more efficient than contracting them out to private operators, while
privatizing public infrastructure for private profit has typically
led to increased inefficiency and corruption.
State-owned-projects
can keep user fees to a minimum and recoup public investment from
increased tax receipts generated by economic growth. Many
counterproductive cases are cited in a large body of work on
privatization, including my article cited immediately above. Much of
the blame for the current housing credit crisis can be laid at the
footstep of the privatization of government sponsored agencies,
namely Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Privatization
of the public sector in China is not simply the benign
transfer of ownership from the state, as a political institution
representing all the people, to corporatized entities controlled by
private financial institutions and private individual shareowners.
Rather, it is the very process by which the
system of private property is reintroduced into the public sector,
a socialist society in the process of transitioning to a socialist
market economy. This involves fundamental questions about social
justice in ownership distribution, valuation of assets being
privatized, and the fairness of the privatization sale process of
state-owned assets.
Privatization for transitional economies
requires not only the restructuring of the economy but also the
creation or redefinition of private property rights and market
institutions and mechanism while ensuring maximum economic growth
with minimum socio-economic and political disruption. Above all, the
issue of social justice needs to be a controlling consideration.
Ronald Coase, 1991 Nobel Laureate in economics, developed the
Coase theorem in his 1937 paper describing the economic
efficiency of financial allocation in the presence of externalities.
Externality in economics involves
impacts on parties not directly engaged in economic decisions or
actions, or in plain language: the spillover
effect. Externality in finance occurs when others besides the actors
must pay for the cost or share the benefits of a decision, action or
transaction.
The theorem, clarified in his 1960 article "The
Problem of Social Cost", states that when trade in an
externality is possible with no transaction costs bargaining will
naturally lead to an efficient outcome regardless of the initial
allocation of property rights. By extention, given well-defined
property rights, low bargaining costs, perfect competition, perfect
information and the absence of wealth and income effects, resources
will be used efficiently and identically regardless of who owns them.
The Coase theorem has been cited as a basis for most modern
economic analyses of government regulation. According to Coase,
disputes over resources stem mostly from a situation where no
one owns them, as in the case of nature, or everyone
owns them, as in the case of public property. However, these
disputes could be resolved automatically if the unclaimed resources
were divided up as private property, even if the division contain
inherent unfairness.
The folly of privatization
This
is the basic argument used by those promoting privatization of the
public sector. They view the problem of air pollution as no one
owning the air, or everyone owns it. The same argument applies to
water. If these natural resources were privatized, economic efficient
[efficiency] over their use and preservation would improve,
these privatizers argue. But the nature of the economic man is such
that whoever is assigned to own the air would
rather charge others for permission to pollute it than to pay
everyone else to stop polluting it. Privatization of air would
then end up promoting air pollution for profit.
Another
obstacle to applying the Coase theorem is the wealth and income
effects. This is defined as the change of wealth or income that
occurs when public property or property rights are awarded unevenly
to private parties. Coase made his "invariance claim" that
outcomes will be similar of not identical regardless who the favored
owners are. But effects of wealth and income disparity on equality
and social stability are ubiquitously obvious enough to invalidate
the Coase theorem.
Coasians argue that the social results may
be different, but they will be equally efficient economically. The
problem with this argument is that changes in supply and demand
caused by different ownership patterns have rippling effects
throughout the entire economy that affect efficiency. And even if
efficiency is unaffected, social stability will certainly be affected
that will in turn affect economic efficiency.
History has
shown that no national resurgent strategy can succeed without a clear
understanding of the importance of a viable
monetary strategy for successful independent national
development. Chinese monetary strategy in recent decades has been
reactive, lacking political will to take the initiative and playing a
game in ways that show her policymakers as not
having full understanding or the necessary skills to control the
outcome, despite the fact that China has become the world's biggest
creditor nation and the top manufacturer.
China cannot
continue to allow her currency to be a derivative of the dollar; nor
can she rely on a foreign trade surplus denominated in dollars to
finance much-needed domestic development. China must stop further
privatization of her public sector, stop exposing her strategic
sectors to international market forces and take steps to reverse the
disparity of wealth and income and free up sovereign credit to
develop much need physical and socio-economic infrastructure at a
much faster pace.
After three decades of reform and
opening-up to the outside world, Chinese
policymakers should realize its time to review and redirect toward
new approaches of national revival not merely to catch up with a
decadent West, but to restore Chinese civilization as the guiding
light towards a world free of exploitation and oppression.
Next:Fulfilling China's national
destiny
Henry C K Liu is chairman of a
New York-based private investment group. His website is at
http://www.henryckliu.com.
(Copyright 2008 Asia Times Online
(Holdings) Ltd. All rights reserved. Please contact us about sales,
syndication and republishing.)