6/4 Antal Fekete - THE LAST CONTANGO IN
WASHINGTON
Copyright 2006 © by A. E. Fekete
THE
LAST CONTANGO IN WASHINGTON
Antal E. Fekete
Professor
Emeritus, Memorial University of Newfoundland
When the silver
corpse stirs, money doctors run
People from around the world
keep asking me what advance
warning for the collapse of our international monetary system,
based as it is on irredeemable promises to pay, they should be
looking for. My answer invariably is: "watch
for the last contango in silver".
It takes
a little bit of explaining what this cryptic message means. Contango
is that condition whereby more distant futures prices are at
a premium over the nearby. The opposite is called backwardation
which obtains when the nearby futures sell at a premium and
the more distant futures are at a discount. When contango gives way
to backwardation
in all contract spreads, never again to return, it is a
foolproof indication that no deliverable monetary silver exists.
People with inside information have snapped it up in anticipation of
an imminent monetary crisis.
"Last contango" does
not mean that the available supply of monetary silver has been
"consumed" by industrial applications, as trumpeted by the
cheerleaders of the get-rich-quick crowd. Such a notion is at odds
with the fact that silver has always been, and still is, a monetary
metal. Huge stores of monetary silver still exist, but are kept out
of sight and availability by their current owners who, for obvious
reasons, want to remain anonymous. "Last contango" is
the endgame of the grand tug-of-war between the money doctors and
"We, the People". The doctors exiled silver from
banking to the futures market hoping that it will drown there in a
sea of paper silver. But the silver corpse stirs. People withdraw
ever greater chunks of cash silver from exchange-approved warehouses.
The money doctors run scared. If futures trading in silver is
unsustainable and must end in default, then the flimsiness of the
house of cards built of irredeemable promises will be exposed for all
to see. Following the last contango in Washington the money doctors,
led by Helicopter Ben, will follow the example set by the 18th
century Scottish adventurer John Law of Lauriston. He left Paris in a
hurry. In a disguise. Disguised as a woman.
Don’t kill
the goose laying silver eggs
My main argument justifying the
claim that the bulk of monetary silver has not been consumed is that
silver, just as gold, is far more useful in monetary than in
industrial applications. Provided, I hasten to add, that you know
what a monetary metal is, and you also know
how to make it yield a return. Admittedly very few people
do, and fewer still are willing to share their knowledge with others.
Nevertheless, monetary applications of silver are real. Industrial
applications kill the goose that lays silver eggs. We must also
remember that silver consumption is a relative concept. In
Newfoundland tiny silver pieces half the weight of a silver dime with
5 cent denomination had been in circulation before 1949. After the
country was absorbed into Canada, these pieces were threaded onto a
chain to form bracelets and necklaces. You may, of course, say that
silversmiths have "consumed" silver but, clearly, these
pieces could re-enter circulation if circumstances warrant it, as
quickly as overnight. While the labor component of the price of
silver cutlery and plate may be greater, again, this is relative. At
a higher silver price it may become negligible. There is hardly any
form of silver consumption the product of which could not be
recycled, provided only that the silver price is high enough.
The
hairy tale of naked short interest
Every time the silver price
rallies, selling appears and the price falls back. "Aha",
the cheerleaders cry, "the ‘silver managers’ are at
it again. They are selling silver naked!" Since the silver
managers issue no denial, it is taken as a confirmation of the hairy
tale of naked short selling.
According to this fable the
silver managers gang up against silver investors in an effort to
drive down the silver price, so that they may cover their naked short
positions at a profit. But if this were true, wouldn’t they
sell into weakness rather than into strength? The fact that an
increase in the short commitment invariably occurs on rallies and it
is then reduced on subsequent dips clearly indicates the absence of
malicious intent. Traders simply take advantage of the variation in
the silver price in order to derive profits from it, much the same
way as hydro plants take advantage of the tides in order to harness
its energy. Nobody suggests that the tide-ebb cycle is caused by the
hydro plants. It is interesting that the cheerleaders don’t
complain when the silver managers buy on dips. They put a different
spin on it. Purchases are described as the last desperate attempt of
the silver managers at short covering.
Soon enough this fable
of a huge phantom naked short position will be put to the test.
According to the cheerleaders the short interest should cave in under
the burden of unbearable losses. The silver managers will throw in
the towel, and panic-covering will cause the silver price to go to
four digits, non-stop. "Patience, fellow silver investors,
patience! Hang on just a wee-bit longer! After this last sell-off the
price will go straight up!" Well, we have heard that battle-cry
often enough, long enough. It is getting monotonous, perhaps a little
boring as well.
So where do we go from here? The cycle of
profit-taking/bargain-hunting/short-covering will, of course,
continue as before. Volatility will grow, quite possibly faster than
the moving averages, maybe far exceeding anything we have seen so
far. The silver price could be up $100 one day, and down $100 next
day, so that a relative top may be indistinguishable from an absolute
top. Lots of investors will be bumped from the band-wagon
prematurely, and they may find it impossible to climb back. But
silver to go to four digits in one fell swoop? No way. Unless
Helicopter Ben’s deeds are as good as his bluffing, and the
air-drop of Federal Reserve notes does start in earnest.
Hedging
or streaking?
I do not deny that naked short sellers exist.
They do. I prefer to call them "streakers". Remember
"streaking", the fad of the 1970's? Young men derived
excitement through exhibitionism as they ran short distances stark
naked in busy streets. If the commercial traders ever run naked, it
is likewise for fleeting moments only. They cover at the first
opportunity. Then they may streak again and cover again. It must be
exhilarating. I am not so sure about its profitability, though.
I
go further. What passes as "hedging" by gold and silver
mining concerns is also streaking. If the miners were hedgers, then
they would plow output into a monetary metal fund and write covered
call options against it. But this is not what they do. They sell
forward their future output, essentially selling naked, sometimes
going out as many as 5 years. Then they cover part of their short
position through purchases of call options. You can hedge cash gold,
but you cannot hedge gold locked up in ore
deposits deep underground that will take 5 years to bring up and
unlock!
"Hungry pig dreams of acorn"
To
call the gold miners’ forward selling "hedging" is a
gross abuse of language. It should not be permitted by the
watchdog agencies. It is an instance of wilfully misinforming the
public. According to a Hungarian proverb "hungry pig dreams of
acorn". The wheat farmer selling wheat futures before harvest is
not hedging. He is selling forward in order to lock in a favorable
price. He is barred from selling anything in excess of his current
crop. It would be tantamount to selling dreams. Likewise, the
gold miner should also be limited to selling forward one year’s
production.
In any case, it is not the
producer who hedges but the warehouseman. If the producer calls
his forward sales "hedges", then he is obfuscating. He
wants the buyers of futures contracts to believe that they are buying
something more substantial than the dreams of a hungry
pig.
Streaking as practiced by gold and silver mining
concerns, in contrast with hedging proper, is a deeply flawed
strategy animated by Keynesian and Friedmanite precepts. The basic
assumption is that spikes in the gold and silver price are an
aberration and, hence, must be temporary. Prices, as everything
in economics, are bound to revert to the mean. The regime of
irredeemable currency is here to stay. The money doctors have
perfected methods whereby we can avoid the pitfalls into which the
early pioneers of fiat currency fell. Take, for instance, the
helicopter. The money doctors of the French Revolution had to labor
without the benefit of air drops of assignats.
Helicopter and
guillotine in aid of monetary policy
This is not the place to
refute Keynesian and Friedmanite fallacies. Suffice it to say that
the helicopter is a dubious asset in the hands of the Federal Reserve
Chairman anxious, as he is, to get his freshly printed
"I-owe-you-nothing" notes into the hands of the public
instantaneously. On the liability side the Chairman does not have the
benefit of another great invention readily available to the managers
of the assignat, namely the guillotine. As is known, during the
French Revolution the guillotine was used, among others, for the
purpose to cap the price of gold with good effect.
[“Law of Maximum Price. See Doug Casey's 'Fiat
Money: History Repeats Itself'
here
.] So much for hi-tech. As for lo-tech, absolutely nothing has
been learned by monetary science during the past 200 years to justify
the claim that money doctors can indefinitely entice people to give
up real services and real goods in exchange for irredeemable promises
to pay. The dictum of Lincoln still stands: you can fool some people
all the time; you can even fool all the people some of the time; but
you cannot fool all of the people all of the time.
Money is
not what the government says it is but what the market treats as
such. Silver and gold have been demonetized by the government through
trickery and chicanery: silver in the 1870's and gold a century
later, in the 1970's. Markets have never ratified these government
measures and, presumably, never will in view of the disastrous record
of fiat currencies. Witness the helicopter and the guillotine, the
carrot and stick of monetary policy.
The principle of reversal
to the mean doesn’t work for monetary metals. Silver and gold
mining concerns will find to their chagrin that their streaking
strategy is backfiring. They are facing horrible losses on their
naked short positions. They can thank their plight to their Keynesian
and Friedmanite mind-set, and to the brainwashing that passes as
research and education in economics departments at all the
universities and think tanks of the world today.
Basis,
the best kept secret of economics
How many
gold mining executives are familiar with the concept of basis? Maybe
one in ten. And how many can use it effectively in marketing gold?
Maybe one in a hundred. Don’t look for a chapter on basis in
Samuelson’s Economics. It is not there. Don’t try to find
its definition in Human Action of Mises. It is not there either. You
have to go to obscure manuals on grain trading produced by
professionals for the benefit of professionals to learn what it is.
As far as I can tell no economist has ever written about it for the
benefit of laymen.
The basis
earns its name by serving as the most
basic trading tool and precision instrument of the grain elevator
operator. In buying and selling grain he is not guided by
the price and its variation. He is guided by the basis and its
variation. He stands ready to buy or sell 24 hours a day, 7 days a
week. If you wake him up in the dead of the night with an offer, he
won’t ask your price. He will ask your basis.
[Your basis is (NearFuture – YourAskPrice).] If he likes
it [
Your basis >= His bid basis. That is,
(NearFuture – YourAskPrice) >= (NearFuture – HisBidPrice). Or equivalently,
YourAskPrice <= HisBidPrice .
] , then it’s a deal,
regardless of the price. Professional buyers and sellers of grain do
not quote their bid/asked price. They have no use for it. They quote
their bid/asked basis.
Recall that basis
is the spread between the nearest futures price and the cash price.
The grain elevator operator buys cash grain during the harvesting
season to fill his elevators to the brim. He tries to buy cash grain
at the widest possible basis (known as carrying
charge). He is planning to sell it when the basis is getting
narrower. His profit is just the shrinkage of
the basis. What is the explanation of this peculiarity? When
the grain elevator operator buys cash grain, he sells an
equivalent amount in the futures market. (He must hedge his
inventory because the capacity of his elevator storage space is so
huge that even a minor fall in the grain price will wipe out his
entire capital, if his cash grain is left unhedged.)
During
the growing season the basis keeps falling as inventories are being
drawn down. The grain elevator operator tries to sell cash grain at
as low a basis as possible, because he expects to replace it at a
wider basis when the new crop becomes available. It goes without
saying that in tandem with selling cash grain he lifts his
hedges, i.e., buys back his contracts to deliver cash grain
in the future. I repeat, from the point of view of profitability, the
prices at which he bought and sold cash grain don’t matter. The
only thing that matters is the variation of the basis.
Sometimes he buys cash grain at a higher and sells it profitably at a
lower price. How can he get away with this prestidigitation? Well, he
has correctly anticipated that the basis will shrink faster than the
price will fall. He is aware that he cannot predict the variation of
the price, which is at the mercy of nature. But he may divine the
variation of the basis that depends on human need, which is
more predictable.
Rationing warehouse space
Moreover,
the basis also helps the grain elevator operator to decide what type
of cash grain to buy and store. Other things being the same he
will buy the grain with the higher basis, and sell the one with
the lower. In this way he can maximize his profit derived from the
shrinking basis. If the basis is higher for wheat than for corn, then
he will keep buying cash wheat in preference to corn until the basis
for corn catches up. Or, suppose, the news is that corn blight has
hit the growing regions. The astute grain elevator operator will
respond by accelerating his sales of cash wheat, in order to make
room for more corn in his elevators.
The best way to think
about the business of the grain elevator operator is to assume that
he is marketing warehousing services,
including the rationing of warehouse space between competing uses.
His guiding star is the basis. High and rising basis tells him for
which purposes the demand for scarce public warehouse capacity is the
most urgent. Low and falling basis tells him for which purposes the
demand is slack, as people prefer non-public solutions for their
storage problem, e.g., by keeping supplies closer to home, as often
happens in troubled times. Including digging holes in one’s own
backyard.
The
idiosyncracies of the basis with regard to monetary commodities,
since they can be buried in holes, are quite different from those
with regard to non-monetary commodities, which cannot.
This will be the subject of the last of this 3-part series on the
basis.
Acknowledgement
I am grateful to Dr. Theo
Megalli for calling my attention to the work of the German monetary
scientist Heinrich Rittershausen (1898-1984) who apparently was the
first to make the distinction between monetary and non-monetary
commodities, observing that the former fails to follow the
conventional demand/price schedule, in his treatise Monetary Theory,
now also available in English translation, see: .
Dr. Megalli
also quotes the remark that has earned many enemies to Rittershausen
in banking, commercial, and industrial circles, not to mention
political circles, a remark that deserves to be better known: "It
was not the gold standard that failed, but those to whose care it had
been entrusted".
Correction
I want to
thank several readers, too numerous to mention by name, who pointed
out to me an error in my last piece Monetary vs. Non-Monetary
Commodities, see: Under the caption Big Lie Number Two, in discussing
the strategy of writing covered options, I mistakenly suggested that
stop-buy orders, placed at points where the call options would be
exercised, would kick in as the gold price fell. However, a stop-buy
order would in fact kick in as the gold price rose. The tenor of the
paragraph is also misleading. It suggests that the strategy can be
put on auto-pilot, which is a rhetoric exaggeration. In fact, the
strategy calls for careful management.
June 3, 2006.
Copyright 1999 - 2006 Le Metropole Cafe. All rights
reserved.